Breeding Competitive Strategies
David F. Midgley,
Robert Marks and
Lee G. Cooper
Working Papers from Santa Fe Institute
Abstract:
We are interested in the strategic implications of asymmetric competition. Previous work (Carpenter, Cooper, Hanssens and Midgley [CCHM] 1988) has estimated the Nash-equilibrium prices and advertising expenditures for asymmetric market-share models in the extreme cases of no competitive reaction and optimal competitive reaction. There are, however, three important limitations to building marketing plans on either of these competitive scenarios.
First, such static, single-period strategies do not provide insight into the actions undertaken over time by major manufacturers and retailers. Strategies such as ad pulsing versus more continuous exposures, or every-day-low-pricing versus deep discounting are played out over time. As we called in the CCHM study, it is time to investigate dynamic, multiperiod strategies.
Second, major sources of asymmetries are missing from the CCHM equilibrium analysis. There are two main sources of asymmetries. Asymmetries can arise from stable, cross-competitive effects. The price-tiers hypothesis (Blattberg and Wisniewski 1989), for example, indicates that when national brands go on sale they exert a stable, competitive pressure on regional brands that the regional brands can not counter with their own price reductions. When regional brands go on sale they exert pressure on the economy and private-label brands that these brands can not return. These are asymmetric cross-competitive effects. One brand on sale by itself might gain much more than if it was promoted along with four other brands in the category. The distinctiveness of a brand's offering can produce asymmetric competition in a particular choice context (Nakanishi et al. 1974, Cooper and Nakanishi 1983 and 1988). While the CCHM study incorporated measures of distinctiveness into their development of methods for reflecting asymmetric competition, the equilibrium analysis used a simpler model that did not account for this source of asymmetries.
Third, the CCHM effort studied market share, while the great swings in sales levels we observe in retail scanner data encourage us to study the strategic implications of asymmetric sales response. We want to investigate multi-period strategies, when the market response is fundamentally asymmetric in both sales volume and market share.
There are major barriers to traditional avenues of investigation. Mathematical exploration is hampered because sources of asymmetry explicitly violate the global0-convexity requirements of normative economic models. One major alternative to mathematical exploration is multi-period simulations, such as Axelrod's first tournament (Axelrod 1984) or the fader/Hauser tournament (Fader and Hauser 1988). While these have the advantage of allowing strategies to be played out over time, so far they have only been undertaken with symmetric and hypothetical market-response functions. We want to use asymmetric market-response functions that characterize brand behavior in real, markets to study the evolution of robust strategies.
Genetic algorithms (Holland 1975) provide a mechanism by which we can pursue the study of the evolution of robust strategies. The next section describes genetic algorithms and how adaptable they are to the study of marketing strategy. This is followed by a discussion of a regional U.S. coffee market previously analyzed from a perspective of asymmetric competition (Cooper 1988, Cooper and Nakanishi 1988). Data from an asymmetric model of this market are then used along with a genetic algorithm to breed simple artificial agents for this market. We will demonstrate that in the limited tests we can feasibly conduct these agents outperform the historical actions of brand managers in this regioal market. Finally, we will discuss the reasons why this might be so and what canb e done to extend our approach.
While we will primarily focus on one set of market modeling techniques, and one particular market, it is important to stress that the methods we propose have greater applicability. Indeed they canb e used in any marketing situation where there is a good representation of the profit consequences of competitive marketing actions. This representation might be in the form of an explicity linear or nonlinear model or it might be more of a "black-box" representation (e.g., numerical approximation or neural net). Given such a profit function, artificial agents can be formulated and genetically optimized to play multiperiod dynamic games in a robust and profitable manner. Our emphasis on asymmetric market modeling in the CCHM tradition, and on a regional coffee market, simply provides one case illustration of the overall approach.
Date: 1995-06
References: Add references at CitEc
Citations: View citations in EconPapers (12)
There are no downloads for this item, see the EconPapers FAQ for hints about obtaining it.
Related works:
Journal Article: Breeding Competitive Strategies (1997) 
This item may be available elsewhere in EconPapers: Search for items with the same title.
Export reference: BibTeX
RIS (EndNote, ProCite, RefMan)
HTML/Text
Persistent link: https://EconPapers.repec.org/RePEc:wop:safiwp:95-06-052
Access Statistics for this paper
More papers in Working Papers from Santa Fe Institute Contact information at EDIRC.
Bibliographic data for series maintained by Thomas Krichel ().